Economic collapse is inevitable

Welcome to the Precious Metals Bug Forums

Welcome to the PMBug forums - a watering hole for folks interested in gold, silver, precious metals, sound money, investing, market and economic news, central bank monetary policies, politics and more. You can visit the forum page to see the list of forum nodes (categories/rooms) for topics.

Please have a look around and if you like what you see, please consider registering an account and joining the discussions. When you register an account and log in, you may enjoy additional benefits including no ads, market data/charts, access to trade/barter with the community and much more. Registering an account is free - you have nothing to lose!

People liken the disintegrating economy to watching a train wreck in slow motion. I disagree.

A more apt illustration is, the train is on a steep downgrade, the brakes are failed, and at the bottom is a sharp curve just before a washed out bridge over a deep ravine.
 
I think things are going to begin to accellerate pretty soon. With guys like Soros dumping all of his financial stocks and buying up gold, it is but a matter of time now.

Time to prep it up is coming to a close.
 
Last edited:
Until Japan collapses, I won't accept economic collapse as inevitable. :)

So why hasn't Japan collapsed yet?

Interesting read here:

http://gulfnews.com/business/opinion/japan-s-fiscal-crisis-comes-of-age-1.1063583

Key excerpts:

The only reason that Japan has been able to sustain its fiscal position is that 93 per cent of its debt is domestically held (with the Bank of Japan now buying close to one-third of the JGBs issued each year).

Moreover, Japan’s private sector — its households and companies — sits atop a mountain of savings, which is mostly used to purchase JGBs. Because the government can still borrow mainly from the Japanese people, its balance sheet remains stable. But, given Japan’s ageing population, how long can that continue?
 
Last edited:
Kyle Bass laid out his argument a while back about the inevitability of Japan's collapse. Their aging population was the key. We have the same issue with the baby boomer generation, but we're not as far along on the curve yet.
 
Good post on zero-hedge today about Japan:

http://www.zerohedge.com/news/when-...the+survival+rate+for+everyone+drops+to+zero)

It is hard to find fiscal situations that are worse than Japan's. The gross government debt/GDP ratio, at more than 200%, is the worst among the major developed economies. Yet yields on Japanese government bonds (JGBs) have not only been among the lowest, they have also been stable, even during the recent deterioration during the European debt crisis. This apparent contravention of the laws of economics is both an enigma for foreign investors and the reason for them to expect fiscal collapse as a result of a sharp rise in selling pressure in the JGB market. As Goldman notes, the European debt crisis has led to an increase in market sensitivity to sovereign risk in general and questions remain on when to expect the tensions in the JGB market and the fiscal deficit to reach a breaking point in Japan. In the following 14 charts, we explore the sustainability of fiscal deficit financing in Japan and Goldman addresses the JGB puzzles.







Goldman Sachs: Japan’s fiscal/JGB enigma and conceptual framework

A financial crisis can come about as a result of a lack of solvency or liquidity. Solvency is a government’s ultimate ability to pay its debts. Liquidity is concerned with the “here and now”: can a government fund its ”current” fiscal deficit in a particular fiscal year? In terms of solvency, there are massive concerns about Japan. Despite these concerns, domestic investors have poured funds into the JGB market. As a result, Japan currently has no liquidity problem at all, which may seem strange at first glance.





Even the government’s primary balance forecast, based on a growth-strategy scenario that is far more optimistic than private-sector forecasts, does not predict primary surpluses in the next ten years (it assumes a total of 5 percentage point increase in the consumption tax rate until October 2015). We conclude from this that Japan’s debt/GDP ratio can only be stabilized through deep spending cuts that will necessarily include cuts in areas such as social security, and believe this will be extremely difficult to achieve politically.





One reason why Japanese investors continue to invest in JGBs despite solvency concerns is that firms are saving sufficiently.









Falling growth expectations as a result of Japan’s ageing demographics have eroded the incentive to invest and borrow. Money with nowhere to go is therefore being channeled into the JGB market via banks and other domestic financial institutions. Even if investors want to move out of JGBs, the funds are so large that there is no yen financial market of an equivalent size and liquidity. There have been some moves into US Treasuries and Bunds but Japanese investors have a strong ”home bias” and such fund transfers have been limited, at least thus far. Money has therefore stayed in the domestic market, funding the fiscal deficit even when negative factors have arisen. Hence, liquidity has so far not been a problem.

Why are JGB yields so low and stable in the face of major solvency concerns? This has been an enigma for foreign investors. We address this question by breaking down the nominal yield into (1) real interest rates, (2) inflation expectations, and (3) a fiscal premium.

(1) The real interest rate is generally approximated by the real potential growth rate over the long term. It has fallen sharply in the past two decades due to rapid ageing of the population. In turn, firms have lost some of their capex incentive and thus shifted from cash shortfalls to cash surpluses.
(2) Inflation expectations have fallen in Japan because nominal wage cuts in the late 1990s have led to widespread deflation expectations.
(3) So far the JGB market has not factored in a fiscal premium to a significant extent. This is very different from the sovereign Credit Default Swap (CDS) market, where pricing is largely determined by foreign investors. Japan’s sovereign CDS spread, which can be seen as an objective assessment of the government’s solvency, has been rising since the late 2000s. We believe the JGB market’s lack of a fiscal premium is due to the stable domestic uptake of JGBs.
Japan’s fiscal sustainability

To assess Japan’s fiscal sustainability, it is therefore more important to look at it in terms of liquidity rather than solvency. Specifically, we need to assess how long the surplus funds of domestic private agents can absorb fiscal deficits. We project this situation out to FY2020 using a two-pronged approach based on an investment/savings identity. Our first, direct approach is to model the savings behaviour of firms and households. Our second approach is to start from the current account balance, which is equivalent to the overseas sector’s savings that appear as the result of our first approach. This is an indirect method for exploring the domestic potential for fiscal deficit funding. The two approaches complement each other, with reality likely to be somewhere between the two simulations.





The most important underlying factor in our first approach is population ageing.









This is a negative for household savings but positive for corporate savings. To gauge the outlook for domestic uptake of fiscal deficits, we combine our estimates for the cash surpluses of domestic private agents with the government’s forecast for the fiscal deficit.





In a scenario where the deficit is not reduced by more than what the current government plans and the fund outflow of overseas M&A by Japanese firms is taken into account, we find that it would become difficult to fully finance the deficit domestically by FY2018. However, the Japanese government is considering another consumption tax hike beyond the currently-planned 5% increase by FY2015. Thus, for example, if we apply a hypothetical (but realistic, in our view) scenario of a further three percentage point increase in consumption tax rate or an equivalent cut (at least ¥6tn) in permanent fiscal expenditure, we find that the deficit can comfortably be funded domestically through FY2020, the end of our analysis period.





However, we note that measures such as the currently-planned five percentage point increase in consumption tax rate are far from sufficient to solve the solvency problem as they do not address the issue of stabilizing the debt/GDP ratio. We believe they are just stopgap measures to keep the wheels turning even as domestic savings dry up.



Current account outlook

Our second approach is to look at the current account outlook in that it will move into deficit if domestic cash surpluses are unable to finance the fiscal deficit. We simulated the current account up to FY2020 using conservative assumptions: further yen appreciation, offshore production shifts by manufacturers and continued imports of energy alternatives to nuclear power. Our conclusions are as follows:

If overseas production shifts continue at their historical pace (taking the overseas production ratio to 24% in FY2020, from about 18% in FY2010), we would not expect the current account to move into deficit by FY2020.





We would likely see widening trade deficits as (1) offshore production reduces exports and increases imports, and (2) imports are boosted by alternative energy sources. However, large trade deficits are not expected to occur quickly because a fall in exports acts as a curb on imports.

The income account, which has been at the heart of current account surpluses since the mid-2000s, features an increase in earnings from direct investment as a result of offshore production shifts. This mitigates the effect from the widening trade deficits and results in a very gradual deterioration of the current account.

However, in an extreme case where the shifts far exceed their historical pace, taking the overseas production ratio to 33% in FY2020 from around 18% in FY2010, trade deficits would widen much more quickly and the current account would likely move into deficit in FY2019.

The foreign incentive to invest in JGBs

The foreign ownership ratio for JGBs has risen to 8.3% (as of end-March 2012) from its most recent low of 5.7% (end-March 2010), prompting two questions among foreign investors in particular: (1) Why has the JGB yield not risen along with foreign ownership ratio (why are foreign investors not demanding a fiscal premium)? and (2) Will the foreign presence escalate to, say, well above 10% in the near future?

A key point in respect to question (1) is that the increase in the foreign investor presence has been concentrated at the short end.





Although deeply concerned about Japan’s fiscal situation, we believe foreign investors have noted the stable JGB uptake by domestic investors and they do not expect Japan to see a full-blown crisis within the next 12 months or so. They therefore do not require a fiscal premium on short-term JGBs. Forex swap market distortions caused by the European crisis has been another reason for them to invest in short-term JGBs, in our view.

In respect to question (2), we think it depends crucially on how long the European crisis will continue. As long as Europe is in a crisis mode, foreign investors are likely to seek temporary and liquid sovereign safe havens, such as JGBs, as alternatives to European bonds. Thus, we think it is possible that the foreign ownership ratio can increase further from the current 8.3%. That said, we do not expect the ratio to accelerate to far above 10% any time soon. This is because (1) foreign investment has been skewed to the short end and (2) once concerns over the European situation ease, we would likely see foreign investors shift back to European bonds.

Policy implications

We believe it is very difficult for the Japanese government to stabilize the debt/GDP ratio. Our analysis suggests that unless the government makes more aggressive budget cuts than the current plan, domestic funding may become difficult in 6-7 years’ time, meaning that Japan would need more financing from foreign investors. Higher JGB yields would be required to attract foreign investors, possibly triggering a negative spiral in which debt service costs rise and the fiscal situation becomes even more severe.

This is why we think measures such as consumption tax hikes are important. In isolation, they will not stabilize the debt/GDP ratio, but larger annual tax revenues are needed to fund fiscal expenditures, even if this merely keeps the wheels turning. The government will also need to address Japan’s narrow tax base and inefficiencies in tax collection, in our view.

To tackle the solvency issue effectively, we believe the government will need to accompany tax increases with decisive spending cuts, including severe cutbacks in social security spending, although we think deep cuts in social security spending are unlikely in Japan’s current political climate. One important lesson learned from previous fiscal consolidation cases is that the expenditure-cut approach has resulted in substantial debt reduction on average. By contrast, the tax-driven approach tended to have the reverse effect.

Market implications

For the next several years, we do not expect a sharp rise in JGB yields triggered by a sell-off by foreign investors. This is very different compared to the situation in European countries such as Greece and Italy. Although the foreign ownership ratio has increased recently, investment has been skewed towards the short end. Even if we were to see heavy net selling of short-dated JGBs by foreign investors, we would not expect major market jitters given that the Bank of Japan (BoJ) can resort to a variety of operations to increase the supply of funds and thus calm markets.

This leads to the question of whether domestic investors would sell off JGBs on their own initiative. We think the ultimate anchor for domestic JGB investors is the belief that there is scope to cut spending/raise taxes in the future. If this belief is shaken, we would expect them to consider moving out of JGBs. That said, we would still not expect an immediate surge in JGB yields1. Our reasoning is that (1) there is no ready alternative for funds equivalent to twice the GDP of the world’s third-largest economy, and (2) the BoJ is expected to make JGB purchases to support yields.

Another catalyst for a sell-off by domestic investors is if Japanese manufacturers make greater-than-expected overseas production shifts (overseas M&A). Overseas M&A activity has accelerated, driven by shrinking domestic demand and a strong yen, among others. According to our analysis, this trend will bring forward domestic financing difficulties, because such long-term capital outflows cannot be considered as a ready domestic funding source for fiscal deficits. Overseas production shifts also mean a loss of employment opportunities in Japan, which would lead to slower nominal GDP growth, which is closely related to tax revenues in Japan.

Lastly, if Japan’s finances collapse and JGB yields do spiral, we would not expect contagion to the US or Germany given that Japanese investors would likely seek refuge in US and German bonds—in the same way that investors have fled the European crisis—and foreign investors would increasingly resort to ”safer” assets for the time being.
 
Kyle Bass laid out his argument a while back about the inevitability of Japan's collapse. Their aging population was the key. We have the same issue with the baby boomer generation, but we're not as far along on the curve yet.



here's one of his vid's on Japan...

Personally, this dude is dead on. He knows his shit and he speaks plainly.
 
Until Japan collapses, I won't accept economic collapse as inevitable. :)
It is inevitable, although worst case scenario - it might take a loooong time, deteriorating, accompanied with systematic removal of civil liberties - if the central planing encroach continues. See every socialist/communism regime And "regime" is a keyword here - central planned economy is mutually exclusive to free society - if the society is free to make their individual choices - there by definition is no place for central planning. These regimes tend to last a generation (or longer), before collapsing under own weight. In case of Soviet Block, it lasted nearly four generations of misery, before ultimately collapsing. The key was - the satellite countries, that could have been suck dry by a bigger, central power of Moscow. Keeping the population of the central power happy and oblivious, thus giving their politicians free reign.

Quite similar like it is with Washington today. Unfortunately, they (politicians) have a lot of "means of projecting power" to other countries, who dare to think about escaping "Washington block", (i.e. US Dollar). That financial enslavement of some poor bastards resource rich countries, might keep that circus flowing for a good while, I think. All the while, eroding civil liberties, and making Americans more & more dependant on the govt.

It is a black scenario, but that's the nature of the beast - bureaucracy has this build-in tendency to grow in power. And sheeple have that build-in tendency of agreeing to be milked dry.
 
Last edited:
anyone curious why we are no longer hearing anything about an imminent euro apocalypse ? it was all the rage a few weeks ago
we were all on the edge of our seats and banging through the :popcorn:

Is it on hold for the summer hols ?

Or is someone printing furiously ?
 
Excellent post Jay! And great comments!

Gold and savings are what will help us (as individuals) through the likely SHTF coming our way...
 
anyone curious why we are no longer hearing anything about an imminent euro apocalypse ? it was all the rage a few weeks ago
we were all on the edge of our seats and banging through the :popcorn:

...well, it seems that the foam is starting to settle, and political "reality" begins to emerge:

Reuters: "Greece has future in euro zone, analysts increasingly believe"
http://www.reuters.com/article/idUSBRE87G0L620120817

Successive debt bombshells from Greece have so far failed to blow apart the political bonds that hold it in the euro zone, persuading growing numbers of economists to change their minds and conclude that the country's fate lies inside the currency union rather than out.
...surprise, surprise... if you are one of these <redacted - see forum guidelines on epithets>, politicians, than it is always better to plough away against the reallity, than to admit you were wrong on something - like the viability of the common currency in Europe. Minions can always cope with some more shit, it doesn't matter.

Reuters polls over the last few months suggest Greece's euro zone membership has become more secure, in spite of the daily torrent of dismal economic news from Athens, and perhaps even because of it.

The sheer magnitude of Greece's slump has contributed to a growing sense that little remains, in economic terms, that would force lenders to cut off funding to Greece and boot it out the euro zone.
...just like I said - there's nothing really stopping them from defaulting, and STAYING in the Eurozone, practically - just few rules need to be bent, few books need to be cooked, and that's it. And politicians are here to bend these rules, when required.

For economists, Greece's future in the euro zone is no longer an economic question but one of political willpower, which remains firm in Athens and Brussels, in spite of opposition from politicians in Germany.
...now that's a fecking surprise - no sh.t, Sherlock! Well, here's the news, since the inception it was never about just the economics, it was always about the politics, so it is surprising to me that anyone is surprised. The whole Euro project is a political one, the issue of how much German savings will get close shave on reckless lending to/reckless spending in PIIGS countries, is much more of a political issue, than it is an economical one (because economically speaking, these countries are long bankrupt, period), the whole issue of one country leaving the eurozone is as political, as it gets.

Do not make false assumptions, that main drivers will be economic. Only as the last resort, when there's no other choice than to face the music. Not yet, and not for a good while yet.

And finally:
There is now a strong consensus that Greece will still be in the euro zone in 12 months, with 45 out of 64 economists polled last week in agreement. Even as recently as May, opinion was fairly divided.
..see? I told you, they won't exit, unless there's full-on civil war on the streets, with people rioting against the government, demanding it and threatening politicians with a coup. And they aren't, they aren't even in favor of exiting EZ...

..next, lessee about the Spain... In the meantime, there are strong signs of contagion spreading to Germany & other "core" states...

So it is still more of the same. Just the media focus have shifted slightly.
 
As they say, "On a long enough time line, the survival rate for everyone drops to zero." So yes, economic collapse is inevitable but that's not saying anything.

Debt is a human construction, its not a tangible commodity. Overload of debt doesn't become a problem until people lose trust. People can be fooled for a long, long time.
 
As they say, "On a long enough time line, the survival rate for everyone drops to zero." So yes, economic collapse is inevitable but that's not saying anything.
Debt is a human construction, its not a tangible commodity. Overload of debt doesn't become a problem until people lose trust. People can be fooled for a long, long time.

Who's gonna tell Ancona ? :paperbag:

Hes pretty convinced its all gonna fall over and soon

and i still trust the monopoly paper as a means of exchange, simply because everybody else still does. The brainwashing runs deep and wide.

Just as long as my prescious is only in paper for a few days .......
 
Who's gonna tell Ancona ? :paperbag:

Hes pretty convinced its all gonna fall over and soon

and i still trust the monopoly paper as a means of exchange, simply because everybody else still does. The brainwashing runs deep and wide.

Just as long as my prescious is only in paper for a few days .......

Yeah that's the problem. Especially with Japan and their domestically held debt. The Japanese are a very conforming and law abiding people. They will fool themselves until the very end. I really think they can keep that ponzi scheme going for a long time.

An example would be the Fukushima disaster. You would think there would be a mass exodus of people from the surrounding areas and Tokyo. Two weeks later, everything was back to normal. :)
 
Back
Top Bottom